NOTE:  As provided in LFC policy, this report is intended only for use by the standing finance committees of the legislature.  The Legislative Finance Committee does not assume responsibility for the accuracy of the information in this report when used for other purposes.

 

The most recent FIR version (in HTML & Adobe PDF formats) is available on the Legislative Website.  The Adobe PDF version includes all attachments, whereas the HTML version does not.  Previously issued FIRs and attachments may be obtained from the LFC in Suite 101 of the State Capitol Building North.

 

 

F I S C A L   I M P A C T   R E P O R T

 

 

 

SPONSOR:

Moore

 

DATE TYPED:

3/7/03

 

HB

948

 

SHORT TITLE:

Property Tax Yield Control Provision

 

SB

 

 

 

ANALYST:

Smith

 

REVENUE

 

Estimated Revenue

Subsequent

Years Impact

Recurring

or Non-Rec

Fund

Affected

FY03

FY04

 

 

 

 

NFI

 

 

State Revenues or Debt Service

 

See Narrative

 

 

Local Governments

(Parenthesis ( ) Indicate Revenue Decreases)

 

SOURCES OF INFORMATION

 

Responses Received From

 

TRD

 

SUMMARY

 

     Synopsis of Bill

 

House Bill 948 repeals Section 7-37-7.1 NMSA 1978 of the Property Tax Code, commonly referred to as the "yield control" limitation, for tax years beginning in 2004. Section 1 of the proposal stipulates that for tax year 2003, the Department of Finance and Administration (DFA) must calculate and set tax rates as if Section 7-37-7.1 were in effect. Section 39 of the proposal, however, repeals Section 7-37-7.1 of present law for the 2003 and subsequent tax years. Remaining sections of the proposal simply strike references to Section 7-37-7.1 wherever they appear in New Mexico statutes. The measure thus effectively repeals use of yield control after Tax Year 2003. 

 

FISCAL IMPLICATIONS

 

TRD notes that the proposed measure would affect neither property tax revenues imposed for state debt service purposes, nor any revenue sources not subject to the yield control statute. The impact on various revenue sources subject to yield control – primarily county and municipal operating revenues – would depend on fiscal variables affecting each of the several hundred entities whose rates are now subject to yield control, as well as how the measure is implemented.

 

A major effect of eliminating yield control would be to subject non-residential taxpayers to potentially large tax increases as rates remain unchanged while reassessment occurs. Residential taxpayers would be relatively unaffected due to the three percent limit on residential value increases specified in Section 7-36-21.2 NMSA 1978.

 

Second, the current property tax system would lose its automatic adjustment mechanism whereby rates change in the opposite direction of changes in net taxable value. If, for example, the legislature provides a substantial increase in the veterans’ exemption, the present system adjusts rates in a way that prevents revenue recipients from losing revenue.[1]  Without yield control, this would not occur and revenue recipients would discover their income reduced. This is also true in cases where base decreases occur in response to loss of a local business; for example, a copper mine. The negative "valuation maintenance" component in the yield control formula increases rates in response to the loss of base, leaving revenues largely unchanged. Without this mechanism, revenue recipients would be forced to increase tax rates to cover the loss in the tax base.

 

TECHNICAL ISSUES

 

TRD notes that the bill's assumption in Section 1 that DFA sets all rates -- including rates applicable to counties, school districts and other government units subject to the yield control statute -- is incorrect. DFA does not, for example, determine school district or community college rates that are subject to yield control. If the intent is that all rates subject to yield control should be calculated in Tax Year 2003 as if the yield control statute were in place, the proposed measure should be changed to state “all entities will calculate rates currently subject to yield control for purposes of Tax Year 2003 as if yield control were in effect.”

Table 1: County Operating Rates –

 2002 Tax Year

 

 

 

 

 

   

    Actual Operating Rate

County

Rate
Imposed 

Residential

Non-residential

Bernalillo

10.770

5.918

10.520

Catron

10.850

10.850

10.850

Chaves

10.350

6.769

10.350

Cibola

11.850

8.727

10.662

Colfax

10.350

10.350

10.350

Curry

9.850

9.850

9.850

DeBaca

11.850

11.850

11.850

Dona Ana

11.850

7.800

11.850

Eddy

7.500

6.285

7.500

Grant

11.850

6.734

6.864

Guadalupe

11.850

7.578

11.850

Harding

8.850

5.823

8.850

Hidalgo

11.850

10.559

11.850

Lea

8.600

6.679

8.600

Lincoln

11.600

4.599

8.850

Los Alamos

8.850

4.682

6.814

Luna

11.850

7.610

11.850

McKinley

11.850

5.210

11.850

Mora

11.850

6.706

11.078

Otero

11.850

7.245

11.850

Quay

11.850

8.285

10.350

Rio Arriba

11.850

4.506

9.215

Roosevelt

8.850

4.941

8.850

San Juan

8.000

6.285

8.000

San Miguel

11.850

5.262

10.331

Sandoval

10.350

5.189

8.269

Santa Fe

11.850

4.788

9.076

Sierra

11.850

8.091

11.850

Socorro

11.850

10.289

11.850

Taos

11.850

5.206

10.460

Torrance

11.850

11.282

11.850

Union

9.150

6.703

9.150

Valencia

11.850

6.032

11.850

 

2) The proposal provides no guidance on the question of rates imposed when yield control is repealed. One set of rates has been imposed, but these rates have been reduced over time by the yield control mechanism.  The imposed rates are substantially higher than actual rates in many counties, as shown in Table 1.  If the imposed rates were substituted for the actual rates upon removal of the yield control statute, the result would be rather substantial property tax increases in many jurisdictions – particularly against residential properties. An alternative approach would be to require use of actual operating rates resulting from yield control over the last 30 years. The most appropriate method of solving this problem would be to state that rates subject to yield control in effect in Tax Year 2004 are to be the same rates set in 2003, but that various property tax recipients would be allowed to impose remaining rates in the same manner as currently

 

OTHER SUBSTANTIVE ISSUES

 

TRD has provided the following primer on yield control.

 

Background:

The yield control statute was enacted in 1979 in an environment in which properties had not been reassessed for many years in many counties. It was understood that reassessment would generate very large increases in tax obligations in many counties. Assessors were often reluctant to reappraise properties because they feared voters would blame them for the resulting tax increases. The yield control mechanism was therefore developed to limit revenue increases in response to reassessment by reducing rates.  It also works in reverse; loss in aggregate value due to reassessment increases rates as a result of the formula.

 

Yield Control -- An Illustration

The yield control formula moves rates in the opposite direction of value changes. Value increases due to new construction do not affect rates, although the mechanism does allow new construction and increases in the cost of goods and services provided by governments to increase revenue yields.  The formula applies separately to residential and non-residential operating rates.[2] Hence in a particular jurisdiction, residential and non-residential rates are typically different, as shown in  Table 1.

 

An example of yield control’s effects appears in Figure 1. The chart illustrates the relationship between valuation maintenance and Sandoval County operating rates. Figures in the chart are based on simulations performed on spreadsheet files employed by DFA to calculate rates in Tax Year 2002.  The county non-residential operating rate is currently 8.269 mills – as shown in Table 1.  Non-residential taxable value, excluding oil and gas production and equipment properties (not subject to yield control) totals $383 million. Valuation maintenance – increased value due to reassessment – in tax year 2002 totaled $2.089 million. Figure 1 displays effects of varying valuation maintenance in $1 million increments on rates. In all cases the result is a proportionate and inverse change in the county nonresidential operating rate.

 

Figure 2 illustrates how the rate changes translate into revenue changes. The horizontal line in Figure 2 represents revenues after valuation maintenance changes shown in Figure 1 are made. Revenues do not change because rate changes shown in Figure 1 precisely offset assessed value changes from changes in valuation maintenance. The “dashed” line in Figure 2 illustrates what would occur without yield control in response to changes in valuation maintenance. It assumes the operating rate remains at its current 8.269 mill level. Hence changes in valuation maintenance generate proportionate changes in revenues. Vertical differences between the dashed and solid lines in Figure 2 represent revenue losses or gains to the county that would occur without the yield  control formula.

 

Rationale for Retaining or Eliminating Yield Control

Proponents of eliminating the yield control mechanism favor elimination for one of several reasons. Some of the revenue recipients simply do not like to see their rates reduced in response to revaluation. They recognize that  without the yield control statute their revenues would typically increase at a greater rate than when the formula is employed. Others dislike it because they mistakenly believe the formula was designed primarily to stabilize individual tax bills – an indirect effect of the mechanism. The mechanism does tend to serve that purpose, but individual tax bills are also affected by reassessment and rate changes. If a particular property is assessed at substantially less than market value compared with other properties in a particular county and reassessment occurs, its owner will, and probably should, experience an increase in tax obligations. Hence when taxpayers receive tax increases due to reassessment because their properties are severely underassessed, they often incorrectly conclude that the mechanism does not work.  Properties assessed at values much closer to market value than average under similar conditions experience tax reductions via rate decreases caused by yield control. The net result is elimination of inequities that would happen without reassessment.

Current level of valuation maintenance

 

Revenues under yield control – variable rates

 

Revenues without yield control – constant rates

 
Several other factors suggest that eliminating yield control may be a good idea.  One factor is that it is probably less necessary than in the past due to the recently enacted three percent limitation on residential value increases mentioned above. Another is that without yield control, rates would be much easier to calculate, and perhaps much more readily understood, than rates that result from the yield control formula.

 

There are several reasons why eliminating yield control may not be a good idea. First, if DFA and other agencies ceased yield control, resuming its use would be difficult. Reemploying the mechanism may be appropriate if the three percent valuation increase limitation were eliminated. Secondly, use of yield control in setting nonresidential rates is probably appropriate for the same reason the formula was developed in the first place. Moreover, absence of the revenue limitations produced by yield control might provide strong incentives for some jurisdictions to aggressively reassess commercial properties with resulting tax increases – assuming their assessors did not fear voter retaliation.  Thirdly, as discussed above, changes in the tax base under yield control produce automatic and offsetting changes in rates. Without this mechanism, jurisdictions would be required to make literally thousands of rate imposition decisions in response to changes in the tax base.

 

Some Limitations of Yield Control

The mechanism is far from perfect for several reasons. First, there is no obvious way for revenue recipients to reduce rates under the yield control mechanism. This issue is very complex and would probably require considerable effort to resolve.

 

The second issue may be described as follows: In an ideal property tax system, county assessors would maintain values at "current and correct" levels while rate adjustments maintain revenues at approximately "revenue- neutral" levels as if due to yield control. However, in many New Mexico jurisdictions, most of the rate totals contain debt-service components. Hence when reassessment occurs, governing bodies of entities imposing debt service rates – primarily school districts, although the list includes the City of Albuquerque – often fail to reduce rates. As a result, sometimes there are substantial tax increases from reassessment. Assessors are understandably reluctant to reassess.  Inequities – for example, cases wherein owners of properties whose market value are essentially identical often pay very different property tax bills – are the inevitable result of failure to reassess.  A solution to this “problem” is to apply the equivalent of a yield control mechanism to voter-approved rates and to impose increased disclosure requirements on entities seeking voter approval for bond issues.

 

SS/njw



 

[2] As the text in HB-948 indicates, it also applies to a number of other rates. However, revenues from county and municipal operating rates probably represent the largest sources of revenue subject to the yield control limitation.